40 Field Equations of Economics
We now will derive the main field equations of economics.
The units 1/y and cur./Buy in standard quantity equation disagree, which
should not happen for the variational calculus as
units [.] have to be. Thus we try to
define them in better useable81 quantities for variational
calculus. Instead of the usual dimension of money [currency] we use the more meaningful
money dimension of „purchasing power“ in dimension of buy/cur . The
inverse dimension then is the “value of goods” in dimension
of cur/buy. Thus for the use of Lagrangians in
economy we define VoG:=”Value
of Goods” and VoM:=”Value
of Money” with VoM = 1/ VoG
which leads to:
or
and by definition:
(40.1)
Thus we get:
or
with
and
and like we started in this chapter we get
the matrices:
or
(40.2)
which leads like before to:
(40.3)
which seems to be:
Now we invest again Euler-Lagrange, but now with corrected values:
and
(40.4)
which leads to
with
(40.5)
which results in
gives
gives
gives
The last equation is equal to or
and so we get:
gives
gives
gives
Addition/subtractions/multiplication like before of the main equation now gives:
plus
results in (40.6)
minus
results in (40.7)
plus
results in (40.8)
minus
results in (40.9)
The products of the results then gives
and
(40.10)
which results by division of the two equations in
(40.11)
This nonlinear differential equation
(40.12)
is the Basic Differential Quantity Equation (BDQE) of Economics with Lagrangian applied. We call it basic, as it splits up in just the two main components R and I. Of course it can be split up to any number of components as one needs, but splitting up at least into the two main parts is essential for deeper analysis. The BDQE is rather complicated to solve as it is strictly nonlinear and thus will be delayed to further science in a later issue of this book. But even without explicit solving, which needs some more definition of formulas, the BDQE can be investigated some further.
Next we have to show, that the BDQE is
identical to the common known classical quantity equation MV=HP in the
linear quasi-constant case . For this we have to
assume, that the banks own business I does play no big role of influence
to the GDP, and thus all I-values can be set to be zero. Thus we get
just one component left:, from which we now just can take the root which gives
. Written in
little other notation we will call this the Simplified Linear Differential
Quantity Equation (SLDQE) of Economics:
(40.13)
If the values M, P are assumed to be
quasi-constants, as can be assumed for small differences in time always
approximately (which is done regularly in classical economy), one can multiply
the equation by the needless dt.
And thus one gets of course the classical expression of the classical
simplified linear Quantity Equation (csl-QE) by just
choosing the meaningful positive solution to
The simplified quantity equations are useful, if one needs no deep insights and/or no large time scale of investigation. The classical QE gives, as commonly known, just approximate (locally) valid results. But then we have to use the differential form of it, as we then have to investigate the evolution of the functions in time. And so we may define the altered classical equation
(40.14)
We have used the simeq-sign instead of an equal sign for the linear approximation, which is just to demonstrate the approximate state of any of this linear equations. This is also due to the, in physics well known fact, that every interdependency between two forces always leads in principle to nonlinear differential equation.
Now we derive the Field-Equations:
As systems of linearized differential equations are much easier to solve, the question thus is, when may I linearize the strictly nonlinear differential equation and how far can I go with it? As we could show in the first part of the book, the linear case is given for all times until deep crisis occurs, but after that it can be indeed questioned. For this reason, we start further investigations with the nonlinear BDQE, from which we will get some more insights into the main economic behaviour. The DQE
may be written more simpler with the use of complex
vectors. Such
complex numbers have the usual euclidic metric
defined by using definition of the conjugated complex
with
. But instead of
the usual euclidic norm we define now a special p-norm
for the k-dimensional pseudo-complex vector
:
(40.15) .
This pseudo-complex number is best represented by using a socalled pseudo-riemanian metric represented here by the Minkowsy-tensor
(40.16)
which thus gives the rule for the length of our pseudo-complex vector
of any dimension
(40.17)
with norm
(40.18)
So we can now redefine our two-dimensional basic vectors to
.
With (40.19).
From this follows directly by applying the squareroot and we finally get
(40.20)
the much simpler looking Pseudo-Complex
Differential Quantity Equation (PCDQE). From this arrangement we can see the
fundamentals of economics now more clearly. As we have four vectors of the same
principal form, we see that
both sides of the equation builds up its own footage
area. This can be seen by the fact, that the scalar
product of a vector is given by
= spanned
footage
of the two vectors. Thus the effect of QE is the
fact, that the area spanned by the money supplyand the area spanned by merchandise
has to be equal over time:
(40.21)
which can be thus also written as
(40.22)
whereis the angle
between the R- and I-components on the money side, and
the angle between
the R- and I-components on the merchandise side.
As the vectorsmay have any dimension, we can say that (40.22) is the
Fundamental Geometric Law of Standard Substitutional Economics.
For example, to incorporate wages (W)
and the accompanied labor (L) into the
equation, this can be done by splitting the money supply to the real economyinto the supply
for buying goods (G) and buying labor (wages: W).
Thus we just may define the vectors
;
;
;
as our now 3-dimensional system, where instead of equal areas now equal cubes are to be served. This system of splittings can be done to any desired precision, and thus complexity and dimensionality. By some new greek-symbols for our definition of the p-norm pseudo-complex vectors of any dimension the general nonlinear QE is written as:
(40.23)
Or taking the root, one gets two possible solutions, which have in principle both to be checked for usability:
(40.24)
Hereand
are
pseudo-complex matrices with matrix-summation norm
, vector norm
and the sub-index
denotes the
time-derivative respectively. The in the last equation used Index-notation lets
look the equation much like the classical QE approximation, but it is entirely
of an other deeper meaning. Looking ad the subscripts we see, that the perfect
symmetry is broken now, although on both sides the summation-index-sum spp,t agrees, the
implications for M and H are but indeed slightly different. This
symmetry-breaking between H and M is indeed the most important
fact for growth and crisis as well.